SAN JOSÉ STATE UNIVERSITY
ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT
Thayer Watkins

The Capital Asset Pricing Model

One major step from Portfolio Analysis to the Capital Asset Pricing Model comes from the realization of what determines the risk of a well-diversified portfolio. Our intuition suggests that the riskiness of the stocks in the portfolio would the most important factor. Here our intuition is wrong.

If we workout the algebra of the standard deviation of a portfolio of N different stocks with an average variance of Var and average covariance of Cov the result is:

portfolio = [Var/N + (N-1/N)Cov]1/2

This function is plotted below.

We see from the graph that the risk of the portfolio, as measured by the standard deviation of its rate of return, approaches a lower limit as N increases. What is this lower limit (which is usually called the market risk)? Well the term Var/N goes to zero as N increase without bound, so the average variance drops out of the picture. In the other term (N-1)/N goes to one as N increases without limit so the lower limit is:

limit of portfolio = [Cov]1/2

Thus the only thing that affects the riskiness of a well-diversified portfolio is the average covariance of the stocks in the portfolio. This suggests that the relationship between the rate of return on a stock and the rate of return on other stocks in the market is an important characteristic of a stock.

Another major line of development for the CAPM is through the notion of an optimal portfolio of common stocks, as emerged in Portfolio Analysis. William Sharpe and others asked what the market equilibrium would imply about the composition of the optimal portfolio. The Separation Theorem implies that all investors, to the extent that they bought any common stocks, would always buy in the proportions of the optimal portfolio. This means that if there was any stock that was not in the optimal portfolio there would be no buyers for it. Consequently the price of any stock not in the optimal portfolio would fall. As the price of a stock falls the expected rate of return, dividends divided by price, will rise. (Also the variance of the rate of return and the covariance of its rate of return with other stocks will rise.) This changes the picture and results in a new optimal portfolio. The price of a stock left out of the optimal portfolio will keep falling until it is in the optimal portfolio. Therefore for equilibrium the optimal portfolio must include all stocks in the market. But the conditions for equilibrium imply even stronger restrictions on the optimal portfolio. Suppose that GM stock represents 2 percent of the value of all stock in the stock market but the optimal portfolio were composed of 1 percent GM stock. This would mean that there would be buyers for only half of the GM stock on the market. This would mean the price of GM stock would fall resulting in a change in the composition of the optimal portfolio. The market could not be in equilibrium until the proportion of GM or any other stock in the optimal portfolio was exactly the same as the proportion in the overall market. A portfolio that has the same proportions of stocks as in the overall market is called a market portfolio.

(to be continued)

SJSU ECONOMICS DEPT HOME PAGE

WATKINS HOME PAGE